Salem Witch Trials
By: Jessica • Research Paper • 1,008 Words • January 8, 2010 • 855 Views
Join now to read essay Salem Witch Trials
The need to understand the mechanics of exchange rates and their developments has generated a
vast theoretical and empirical literature. The flexible price monetary model, which subsequently
gave way to the overshooting or sticky-price model, the equilibrium and liquidity models as well as
the portfolio balance approach have characterised three decades of research, from the 1960s to the
1980s. More recently, since the publication of Obstfeld and Rogoff’s (1995) seminal “redux” paper,
the new open-economy macroeconomics has attempted to explain exchange rate developments in
the context of dynamic general equilibrium models that incorporate imperfect competition and
nominal rigidities. Empirically, these theoretical developments have fared poorly at explaining
exchange rate dynamics, at least over relatively short horizons, and several exchange rate puzzles
have been highlighted.
The increasing role played by international financial markets in developed economies
constitutes a persuasive argument to explore possible relationships between returns on risky assets
and exchange rates dynamics. Recently, a new strand of research has investigated the
interconnections between equity and bond returns, on one side, and exchange rate dynamics, on the
other side, with promising results (see Brandt et al., 2001; Pavlova and Rigobon, 2003; Hau and
Rey, 2004 and 2005).
In this paper, by employing the Lucas’ (1982) consumption economy model, we introduce a
new framework explaining exchange rate dynamics. We propose an arbitrage relationship between
expected exchange rate changes and differentials in expected equity returns of two economies.
Specifically, if expected returns on a certain equity market are higher than those obtainable from
another market, the currency associated with the market that offers higher returns is expected to
depreciate. A resident in the market which offers higher expected returns suffers a loss when
investing abroad, and therefore she has to be compensated by the expected capital gain that occurs
when the foreign currency appreciates. This ensures that no sure opportunities for unbounded
profits exist and, therefore, the equilibrium is re-established. Due to the similarity with the
Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP) condition, the equilibrium hypothesis proposed and tested here is
baptised Uncovered Equity Return Parity condition (URP). There is, however, a key difference
between the two arbitrage relations. In the UIP return differentials are known ex ante, since they are
computed on risk-free assets, while in the URP are not.
Risk-averse agents investing in risky assets denominated in a foreign currency usually
require a market and a foreign exchange risk premium, which can be time varying. We begin our
study assuming that investors are risk-neutral, which implies that the URP does not include risk
5
ECB
Working Paper Series No. 529
September 2005
premia. Next, we relax the risk-neutrality assumption and we enrich the URP by employing
additional financial variables, which are related to the business cycle. We use differentials in
corporate earnings’ growth rates, short-term interest rate changes, and annual inflation rates, as well
as net equity flows. In line with previous studies (see, for instance, Fama and French, 1989; Chen,
1991; and Ferson and Harvey, 1991b), these variables can be thought of as proxies for the risk
premia. The URP with risk premia turns out to explain