The Institutional Foundations of China's Market Transition
By: regina • Research Paper • 2,180 Words • December 20, 2009 • 1,126 Views
Essay title: The Institutional Foundations of China's Market Transition
The Institutional Foundations of China's Market Transition
Interpreting China's Transition to Markets: The Institutional Perspective
In the two decades between 1978 and 1998, China has transformed itself from a centrally planned
economy to an emerging market economy and at the same time has achieved nearly a 10 percent average growth
rate. During this period, China's per capita GDP has more than quadrupled and the living standard of ordinary
Chinese people has improved significantly. For instance, per capita consumption has increased four times for
eggs and eight times for poultry, the per person living space has more than doubled in the urban areas and
nearly tripled in the rural areas, and total household bank deposits, measured against the GDP, increased from
less than 6 percent in 1978 to more than 60 percent in 1998. The benefits of the reform were also shared by
the people on a broad basis. The number of people living in absolute poverty has been substantially reduced
from over 250 million to about 50 million in two decades, a decline from one-third to a twenty-fifth of China's
population. Life expectancy on the other hand has increased from 64.37 in the 1970s to 70.80 in 1996 (68.71
for men and 73.04 for women), with infant mortality falling from over 50 per thousand in the 1970s to less than
30 per thousand in the 1990s (China Statistical Yearbook, 1997; Almanac of China's Population, 1997). In
1998, the World Bank moved China's ranking up from a low-income to a lower-middle-income country.1
Such a performance appears more impressive when compared with the average performance of the
transition economies in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. By 1998, with only a few exceptions,
the great majority of these countries still have not recovered to their 1989 output levels according to the official
statistics. The Chinese performance looks even more impressive when considering the fact that transforming
large countries is much more complicated than transforming smaller ones; conceivably, the tasks of
transforming Russia or China are more challenging than those of transforming Poland or Vietnam. At the
outset, China's reform went against all odds: Coming out of the disastrous decade of the Cultural Revolution,
it was poor, over-populated, lacked human capital and natural resources, and was constrained by adverse
2 According to Maddison's (1998) calculation based on purchasing power parity, without taking into account the
1998 Russian economic crisis, China's per capita GDP will surpass that of the 15 former Soviet Union countries by
2010.
2
ideology and political opposition. Two decades ago few economists would have bet on today's outcome of
reform in China.
Even so, China's reform experience has been always viewed as an anomaly in terms of transition to
a market economy, and it has not been properly accounted for by mainstream economics and thus appreciated
by mainstream economists. For example, From Plan to Market: World Development Report 1996 on
transition economies (World Bank, 1996) gave China short shrift because it couldn't figure out where to put
China on the various measurement parameters, and instead illustrated the Chinese experience mainly in boxes
rather than in the text. China simply does not fit the general description of the report. However, the data point
of China is too important to ignore: It has been one of the most successful transition economies, it produced
more than all other transition economies combined in 1998 in terms of GDP, and, moreover, its per capita GDP
is